One barrier to international trade is a tariff. A tariff is a tax that is imposed by a government on imported or exported goods. They are also known as customs duties.
Types of Tariffs
Tariffs can be classified based on what is being taxed:
- Import tariffs: Taxes on goods that are imported into a country. They are more common than export tariffs.
- Export tariffs:Taxes on goods that are leaving a country. This may be done to raise tariff revenue or to restrict world supply of a good.
Tariffs may also be classified by their purpose:
- Protective tariffs: Tariffs levied in order to reduce foreign imports of a product and to protect domestic industries.
- Revenue tariffs: Tariffs levied in order to raise revenue for the government.
Tariffs can also be classified on how the duty amount is valued:
- Specific tariffs: Tariffs that levy a flat rate on each item that is imported. For example, a specific tariff would be a fixed $1,000 duty on every car that is imported into a country, regardless of how much the car costs.
- Ad valorem tariffs: Tariffs based on a percentage of the value of each item. For example, an ad valorem tariff would be a 20% tax on the value of every car imported into a country.
- Compound tariffs: Tariffs that are a combination of specific tariffs and ad valorem tariffs. For example, a compound tariff might consist of a fixed $100 duty plus 10% of the value of every imported car.
Consequences of Levying a Tariff
To see the effects of levying an import tariff, consider the example shown in . Assume that there is an import tax levied on a good in a domestic country, Home. The domestic supply of the good is represented by the diagonal supply curve, and world supply is perfectly elastic and represented by the horizontal line at Pw. Before a tariff is levied, the domestic price is at Pw, and the quantity demanded is at D (with quantity S provided domestically, and quantity D-S imported).
Effects of a Tariff
When a tariff is levied on imported goods, the domestic price of the good rises. This benefits domestic producers by increasing producer surplus, but domestic consumers see a small consumer surplus.
When the tariff is imposed, the domestic price of the good rises to Pt. Now, more of the good is provided domestically; instead of producing S, it now produces S*. Imports of the good fall, from the quantity D-S to the new quantity D*-S*. With the higher prices, domestic producers experience a gain in producer surplus (shown as area A). In contrast, because of the higher prices, domestic consumers experience a loss in consumer surplus; consumer surplus shrinks from the area above Pw to the area above Pt (it shrinks by the areas A, B, C, and D).
Because the tariff is a tax, the government gains some revenue. The government charges a tariff amount of Pt-Pw on every imported good. The amount of revenue is equal to the tariff amount times the number of imported goods, or (Pt-Pw)(D*-S*). This results in a governmental gain of area C.
In this example, domestic producers and the government both gain from the import tariff, and domestic consumers lose. However, if the world price is higher than the domestic price, a tariff will not change the price or quantity consumed of a good.